is clear that nuclear is the best option after coal and can deliver the
required capacity to sustain the Indian exponential industrialization
effort for "only" $17 billion more. If this could be done with nuclear
(which has consistently scaled 40 times slower than coal in India for
the past two decades), the result would be a cut in the economic growth
rate of close to 1% (from 7% to 6%). $17 billion of the potential $147
billion increase in real production would now be used without any real
increase in output (the new nuclear capacity would produce the same
electricity as the coal capacity it displaced). Compounded over 20
years, this would cost India 11% of their potential economic output over
this period.
It is time to start the next chapter of the Seeking Consensus
project: Externalized Costs. This promises to be an interesting chapter
because the spread and uncertainty in the available data is much greater
than it was for internalized costs. As always, I'll be providing a
first estimate for each given energy option together with a simple Excel
model which can be used to come up with new numbers by adjusting
various important parameters.
This post will discuss the
methodology I plan to follow to estimate externalized costs of various
energy options. The general idea will be to split up the external costs
in terms of long-term global externalities (climate change) and
short-term local externalities (e.g. local air pollution).
The
difference between these two types of externalities is that those who
benefit from energy consumption directly experience the negative
impacts of short-term local externalities, but can be separated by
thousands of miles and tens of years from those experiencing the worst
impacts of long-term global externalities. More details on this
distinction are given in two previous articles here and here.
Long-term global externalities (climate change)
Putting
a representative price on greenhouse gas emissions is essentially an
impossible task. Numbers of $30-40 per ton of CO2 are generally accepted
as a reasonable median, but there are many other estimates which lie
far above or below this range. On the high side, we have the "long-tail"
or "95th percentile" estimates which account for the much higher costs
in the case that self-sustaining positive feedback loops are triggered.
On the low side, there are even negative estimates stemming from
positive effects of increased CO2 levels such as increased crop growth
rates.
Then there is also the issue of developed vs. developing
world costs. Due to the low level of economic development, developing
world citizens are generally much more exposed to the effects of climate
change. Storms can completely destroy their homes, heat waves can be
life-threatening, droughts can result in critical shortages of food and
water, and increased temperatures can bring new diseases which can wreak
havoc in the absence of basic medical care. Most of these threats can
be greatly reduced even by moderate levels of industrialization (at the
cost of more fossil fuel consumption). Thus, it makes sense for
developing nations to discount these future climate costs at a high rate
in order to maximize the rate of industrialization in the here and now.
This, in combination with the large historical emissions of the
developed world, implies that the developing world should be allowed a
significantly lower CO2 price than the developed world.
For these reasons the following methodology is proposed: Firstly, the IEA CO2 price estimates for
achieving the 450 ppm scenario recommended by climate scientists is fit
to a function as in the graph above. Following this, the CO2 price is
discounted at the projected growth rate for the developed (2%) and developing (5%) world.
This practice adjusts for the fact that the developing world does not
value rising CO2 costs in the future very highly because rapid growth in
the near term will allow them to handle these costs much more
effectively. In this way, a cost of $53/ton for the developed world and
$24/ton for the developing world can be calculated. Averaging for the
global economy assumed to grow at 3.5% returns a CO2 cost of $36/ton
which agrees well with the median of the wide set of estimates out
there.
Short-term local externalities
Although they are
less prominently discussed than greenhouse gasses, estimates of other
externalities such as localized air and water pollution from fossil fuel
combustion can also be found over a wide range. Naturally, these
numbers vary widely from one energy option to the next and must be
treated separately based on a survey of the available literature in each
individual case.
However, an important additional consideration
will be made in this series: the economic growth benefit experienced by
the local community when not internalizing short-term local
externalities. This is the main reason why many developing world
citizens and governments put up with terrible local pollution as long as
the rapidly growing economy grants them the opportunity to better their
lives.
It is self-evident that more expensive energy will retard
economic development. As an example, the historical correlation between
oil prices and economic growth rates both in the US and Europe are shown
below (data from the USDA database and the BP Statistical Review).
This
is especially applicable to rapidly growing developing economies.
Before we can expect these billions of world citizens to get really
serious about global sustainability, we need to see many more incredible
infrastructure buildouts such as the examples given in this link (the picture of Dubai is shown below).
This
transformation will require many billions of tonnes of steel, cement
and other materials to make billions of modern homes with all the
required water, electricity and sewage infrastructure, many billions of
appliances to fill these homes, many millions of factories and
distribution centres to supply these consumers and billions of cars
driving on many millions of miles of paved roads to connect everything.
All of this will require an absolutely stupendous amount of energy which
needs to be as cheap and as practical as at all possible.
For the
billion or so people who are lucky enough to have all of this in place
already, accounting for such an energy intensive infrastructure
buildout is not necessary, but for the other 6 billion it sure is. This
infrastructure offers large increases in productivity, thus enabling
economies to sustain an exponential economic growth path over several
decades. If local communities choose to make energy more expensive by
internalizing short-term local externalities, even a small growth
slowdown compounds exponentially over time. As shown in the graph below,
even a decrease of only 2% growth sustained over 20 years can cut the
potential size of the economy by over a third. See the appendix at the
end of this article for a simple example illustrating this principle.
To
account for this factor, short-term local externalities will be
multiplied by a factor between zero and one. A factor of zero implies
that costs of internalizing these externalities (reduced growth rate)
outweighs the benefits, while a factor of one implies that
internalization of externalities will have a negligible/positive impact
on growth. Naturally, this factor will be much lower in developing
nations undergoing rapid energy infrastructure buildouts than developed
nations where the capital stock is stagnant or even declining.
Summary
The plan is thus to estimate external costs as follows:
- Climate change: CO2 intensity of the specific energy option in question times a CO2 price of $53/ton for developed nations and $24/ton for developing nations.
- Short-term local externalities (e.g. local air pollution): Median externalized cost for new builds of the specific energy option in question times an adjustment factor for the impact on local economic development. The adjustment factor will vary between zero (economic costs of internalizing externalities outweigh the benefits) to one (internalizing externalities has a negligible/positive impact on growth).
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Appendix: Externalities and growth example
As
a simple illustration of how the internalization of externalities can
cut growth, we can take the example of India which will probably follow
China as the world's next heavily polluted industrialization success
story. Indian GDP and electricity consumption is plotted below on a
log-scale where it is shown that India has maintained almost perfect
exponential growth both in GDP and electricity production over the past
three decades (data from the USDA database and the BP Statistical Review).
To
achieve 7% growth in 2015, India needs to grow real GDP by $147 billion
and its electricity production by 85 TWh. Currently, the vast majority
of this additional electricity consumption will come from dirty, cheap
and practical coal plants. Let's say that India now decides to put heavy
local taxes on coal combustion to internalize short-term local
externalities so that this jump in electricity production must be
achieved by nuclear, onshore wind and solar PV. The graph below gives
the capacity and cost of increasing the electricity supply by 7% using
these four options under the following assumptions: coal (70% capacity
factor, $1000/kW), nuclear (80% capacity factor, $2500/kW), wind (21%
capacity factor, $1200/kW) and PV (18% capacity factor, $1800/kW).
It
is clear that nuclear is the best option after coal and can deliver the
required capacity to sustain the Indian exponential industrialization
effort for "only" $17 billion more. If this could be done with nuclear
(which has consistently scaled 40 times slower than coal in India for
the past two decades), the result would be a cut in the economic growth
rate of close to 1% (from 7% to 6%). $17 billion of the potential $147
billion increase in real production would now be used without any real
increase in output (the new nuclear capacity would produce the same
electricity as the coal capacity it displaced). Compounded over 20
years, this would cost India 11% of their potential economic output over
this period.
For wind and solar, the story is much
bleaker. The required capacity buildout with wind or solar would cost
$55 billion or $97 billion respectively (most of the planned coal
capacity would need to be built anyway due to wind/solar intermittency).
A buildout of half wind and half solar would consume more than half of
the $147 billion GDP increase that would be possible under the standard
coal driven growth path. This would slice the potential size of the
economy in 20 years in half (and more thereafter).
Given
that electricity accounts for only about 40% of primary energy
consumption, these kinds of growth penalties resulting from the
internalization of short-term local coal externalities in the
electricity sector will simply not be acceptable. When seen from the
point of view of the largely impoverished local populace, the economic
benefits of ignoring short-term local coal externalities will outweigh
the costs in most cases.
http://www.theenergycollective.com/schalk-cloete/2253098/seeking-consensus-externalized-costs-energy-methodology
No comments:
Post a Comment