We live in a world with limits, yet our economy needs growth. How
can we expect this scenario to play out? My view is that this problem
will play out as a fairly near-term financial problem, with low oil
prices leading to a fall in oil production. But not everyone comes to
this conclusion. What were the views of early researchers? How do my
views differ?
In my post today, I plan to discuss the first
lecture I gave to a group of college students in Beijing. A PDF of it
can be found here: 1. Overview of Energy Modeling Problem. A MP4 video is available as well on my Presentations/Podcasts Page.
Many Limits in a Finite World
We live in a world with limits. These limits are not just energy limits; they come in many different forms:
All
these limits work together. We can work around these limits, but the
workarounds are higher cost–for example, substituting less polluting
energy resources for more polluting energy resources, or extracting
lower grade ores instead of high-grade ores. When lower grade ores are
used, we need to process more waste material, raising costs because of
greater energy use. When population rises, we must change our
agricultural approaches to increase food production per acre cultivated.
The problem we reach with any of these workarounds is diminishing returns.
We can keep increasing output, but doing so requires disproportionately
more inputs of many kinds (including human labor, mineral resources,
fresh water, and energy products) to produce the same quantity of
output. This creates higher costs, and can lead to financial problems.
This phenomenon is one of the major things that a model of a finite
world should reflect.
Economists Views
Economists
developed their views of the economy long ago, when limits seemed to be
far in the distance. Thus, the models they built do not reflect the
expected impact of limits. They are missing variables that would be
needed to adjust for changes in the economy’s behavior as limits are
reached.
The
story in Slides 3 and 4 tends to be true if we are far from limits, but
is it really true when we are close to limits? Perhaps diminishing
returns as we approach limits changes the results.
World Oil Situation as We Approach Limits
Perhaps
we can get some indication of how diminishing returns are affecting the
economy by looking at historical oil supply and prices. Up until 1970,
US oil production grew quite steadily.
After
1970, oil production suddenly began to decline. Oil companies did not
expect such a decline; they assumed that oil production would rise
endlessly. Once oil production began to decline, oil companies quickly
began trying to find ways to fix their problems. One of these approaches
was quickly to ramp up production in areas that they knew contained
oil, but hadn’t previously been drilled. These included Alaska (northern
United States), Mexico, and the North Sea. Oil production in these
areas is now in decline.
Several ways were also found to reduce
oil usage. These included change from oil to alternate fuels for
electricity generation and home heating, and offering smaller, more
fuel-efficient cars. With this combination of approaches, oil prices
were brought down, most of the way to the $20 level (Slide 7).
The
inflation adjusted level of oil prices is important because oil is the
single largest source of energy use in both the US and world economy. If
oil prices are cheap, it easy to grow food cheaply, and manufacturing
and transport can be done cheaply. Because of this, the economy tends to
grow. If oil prices rise, economic growth tends to slow, because the
cost of many types of goods (including oil products, food, and building
new homes) tends to rise faster than wages. It becomes more expensive to
replace infrastructure such as roads and pipelines as well. The higher
cost of oil effectively acts as a “tax” inhibiting economic growth.
Oil
prices again reached a high level in the early 200os as we again began
to reach limits of the amount of oil that could be extracted at the
then-available price. This time we weren’t able to cut back on world
demand, so prices tended to stay high. Instead, the big change made was
in oil supply, with higher oil prices enabling (after a several years
time-lag) greater production both from US oil from shale formations
(called “tight oil” in Slide 6 above) and from the oil sands in Canada.
The
question becomes: can the economy really function adequately on $100+
barrel oil? Or do the negative feedbacks from these high oil prices have
too adverse an impact on economic growth?
Slide
8 shows more detail regarding production and prices for recent years.
We see that oil prices were generally rising up until mid 2008, and then
dropped steeply. Prices rose again after several types of economic
stimulus were added. More government spending was added, interest rates
were dropped to very low levels and a program called quantitative easing
(QE) began.
Prices stayed at a level a little over $100 barrel
from January 2011 though mid-2014. More recently, oil prices have
dropped to a little more than half of their previous level. This decline
in oil prices appears to correspond to a time when world debt is not
rising as rapidly: the US stopped its QE program, and China’s debt no
longer rising as rapidly. Thus, some of the economic stimulus that
helped hold oil prices up is disappearing.
The problem we are now
encountering is not the high price problem that economists thought would
bring on more supply. Instead, we are encountering a problem with oil
prices that are too low for oil producers to make a profit. Such low oil
prices can quite possibly bring down world oil production, because
investment in oil production is no longer profitable. A person might
ask: Is the low price situation we saw in 2008 and are encountering
again in 2014-2015 what diminishing returns really looks like? Is the problem we encounter as we reach limits one in which oil prices drop too low, rather than rise too high?
In
2008, huge stimulus efforts were required to bring oil prices were
brought back up to the $100+ level. Perhaps one point raised by
economists (Slide 3) was correct: Maybe there is a connection between
economic growth and oil demand. Perhaps the issue as we reach limits is that world economic growth sinks too low,
and it is because of this slow growth that wages stagnate, debt stops
rising quickly, and oil (and other commodity) prices drop too low.
Now let’s look at what some early energy researchers have said.
M. King Hubbert
Many
believers in Peak Oil theory consider M. King Hubbert to be the
originator of their theory. It seems to me, though, that Peak Oilers
have inadvertently picked up some of the economists’ theories, and mixed
them with Hubbert’s theories.
It
seems to me that the only way a Hubbert Curve might happen is if oil
prices stay high, as we approach limits. That way, as much oil as
possible can be extracted. If oil prices fall too low, then the decline
may be much quicker. If low oil prices are a problem, above ground
problems such as governments of oil exporting nations collapsing, or
rising debt defaults leading to bank failures, may be a problem.
Dennis Meadows and Donella Meadows
Dennis
Meadows led early computer modeling efforts at MIT regarding limits of a
finite world. His wife, Donella Meadows, led the write-up effort
regarding this model in a 1972 book called “Limits to Growth”. The model
looked at physical quantities of resources, expected amounts of
pollution, and expected population trends. The base model suggested that
the world would start reaching limits in roughly the current timeframe.
In fact, more recent analyses suggest that the base model is more or less on track.
I don’t think that we can count directly on this analysis, however.
Charles Hall
Prof.
Charles Hall has been one of the recent thought-leaders with respect to
oil limits and how they might play out. He started work in the early
1970s as an ecologist, studying the energy patterns of fish. When he
read about the possibility of energy shortages that might occur in the
1972 book Limits to Growth, he tried to adapt an approach used
for studying energy patterns of fish to the world of energy production.
The result was new way of measuring the efficiency of a particular
energy product, called Energy Return on Energy Invested (EROEI).
This
idea was an advance when it was first developed, but it has a number of
practical difficulties. One of these difficulties is that its
usefulness is tied to a particular view of how oil limits will affect
us, namely that prices will rise, and this will allow a slow transition
to alternative fuels that are less favorable in terms of EROEI. On Slide
21, this is Item (2).
At
this point, it is my view that the EROEI approach to analyzing energy
products can be misleading and needs updating. Energy extraction is much
more complicated than the energy use of fish swimming upstream. The
EROEI approach, besides being tied to the Peak Oil view of how limits
will occur, is difficult to calculate. Different researchers get quite
different answers, when analyzing the same energy product.
Furthermore,
EROEI looks at a piece of energy costs (those involved with production
at the well head), but how this piece relates to the total varies from
one type of energy to another. It lumps together cheap energy and
expensive energy. There are several other issues as well, with the
result being that in practice, low EROEI doesn’t necessarily correspond
to expensive to produce, and high EROEI doesn’t necessarily correspond to low cost to produce.
I
should point out that the same problem exists with a wide range of
similar metrics including Life Cycle Analysis, Energy Payback Period,
and Net Energy. In practice, what seems to happen is that if an energy
type is high-priced, the use of one of these metrics is used to justify
its production, anyhow. Low EROEI (for example, of biofuels) does not
seem to be a barrier to production, even though it was the hope of Prof.
Hall and other EROEI researchers that this would be the case.
My Involvement in Energy Analysis
I
became acquainted with Prof. Lianyong Feng in 2009, when he attended
the Biophysical Economics Conference in Syracuse, New York, held by
Prof. Charles Hall, and heard me speak.
How Do Oil Limits Really Affect the Economy?
This is the question I have been working on. I will try to explain some of my findings in the next several sessions.
Early
researchers were handicapped because the issue of oil limits crosses
many different fields of research. They took approaches from their own
areas of study, and worked with them. These approaches offered partial
insight into the problem, but didn’t completely answer what might happen
in the future.
It was not obvious to early researchers which
parts of economists’ theories were wrong. I have had the benefit of
seeing how the system works in practice in several periods: in
1973-1974, in 2008-2009, and now in 2014-2015. I have also been
fortunate enough to find a number of recent studies that add new
insights as to how the system really works. So I have taken a step back
and developed at the least the start of a new theory, which is different
from EROEI theory. This is what I will discuss in the next few
sessions.
A little explanation behind this series of lectures and
my four week stay in China is perhaps in order. When I was in China,
Prof. Feng discussed with me some of his intent behind asking me to give
this series of lectures. Prof. Hall is now retired, and there is no
obvious replacement for him. Prof. Feng would like me to take a more
active role is figuring out in which direction energy research should
now be headed, both for his own staff, and for others around the world. A
better understanding of how the system works could theoretically help
researchers everywhere.
http://theenergycollective.com/gail-tverberg/2220661/overview-our-energy-modeling-problem
No comments:
Post a Comment